Wednesday, July 28, 2010

Summer & Conference in an Ancient City







Hi guys!

Have you heard about most recent adventures of the Economics Department this Summer- Esin and I travelled to an international conference in Turkey- the Euro meeting of the Society for the Study of Emerging Market Economies. After working for about 2 months on never ending papers, it was time to wrap up results and present them to the opinion of the academic community. I was already in Bulgaria- a neighboring country of Turkey, where are still have most of my relatives and I was planning my trip out of there.

"Planning" in this case should be understood loosely. After sending the kids to a grandma somewhere in a Balkans village area and placing my full concentration on an instrumental variable procedure, my research inspiration got broken up by an unlikely event- my 3-year old laptop (those of you in research understand that this is like a long term friend, since I spend with it more than with my family and friends combined) would not start. I hopelessly pressed the button again and again and finally decided to resort to installing Stata on another machine that was suffering from low hard drive space and find a converter program for all of my Microsoft Office 2007 documents, since the software was unavailable. It was then that my wish got granted and Windows 7 started coming up to life on the otherwise black as no light in the tunnel black screen. The final set of results for my paper still had a chance!

In the last day an half I did not dare closing the lid on my laptop. It stayed running day and night and since, (of course!- what's the fun in doing something you are completely prepared for) the power point slides were not ready yet when I left for the airport, I refused to turn it off for the entire trip. The presentation slides got (of course!) done (what's the point of doing any work, if you are not completely prepared) around 4:30am next morning. At 8:30am I presented our brand new paper about the air pollution impacts of sectoral FDI inflows, in which controlling for simultaneity between income, FDI and pollution, Merih Uctum and I find that most sector's FDI are actually reducing, not increasing air pollution. The paper was well accepted. My laptop (still with the lid open) faithfully served as the session's computer after the session chair did not show up.

The rest was a trivial conference experience with a lot of sessions, meetings and- did I say trivial? This term should be understood loosely as well. There is nothing trivial about Turkey. I started experiencing Turkey from the first flight- from Sofia to Istanbul. Imagine my sheer American surprise when they served me a full dinner on a 1-hour flight. The food was excellent and abundant. Suspecting the same may happen again on the flight from Istanbul to Milas, I was preparing to reject it, but I miscalculated how hungry one gets after getting lost at Istanbul International Airport. (If I ever write "Conference traveler’s Guide to the Galaxy", one of its first advises should be "never change flights in Istanbul"). The airport is close to being completely out of from signs, and where they exist they either point to an ambiguous direction or they count the gates backwards, such as "Gates: 110 to 101". At the return flight, following the signs for International Departures, I discovered the administrative corpus of the airport.

So, I guess Turkish people have invented a way to cope with the energy loss associated with such an environment or it could be that they are keeping it this way purposefully, so they can compensate it with food!
At the conference and down south in Bodrum, the food was over the top. Melons are sweeter than honey and Aegean See Bass is an addiction. If you expect to see me in good physical shape after this summer- don't!

Istanbul is the Balkan's New York- a complete melting pot. It is truly a city of mosques. They are beautiful and majestic. I bought 3 huge books to read about Antique cities in Turkey and about Byzantium. The trip even inspired me to learn more about the ancient sites spread around Bulgaria- sites I have always taken for granted.

Finally, my laptop lasted until the end of the trip and died a hero upon my arrival back in Bulgaria. When I had an engineer do an autopsy on it, he discovered that when its motherboard got exchanged by the manufacturer, since their entire laptop series were sold with defective motherboards, it got exchanged with some other model's motherboard that was not matching the configuration completely and was missing some heat conductors, for example from the video card to the fan. So, I literary burned it out! And yes, I should have said this at the beginning- IT WAS NOT MY WORK COMPUTER; IT WAS MY OWN. The Dell is sitting safely in my office. But I guess, this is a good test for any brand- let me have it for a few days of Stata regressions!

This was my first blog ever and I only did it for the Economics Department. Do not expect me to do it often.

Did you have a Summer full of papers and food too?

Nadia Doytch
ndoytch@newhaven.edu
(July 28, 2010)


Monday, July 26, 2010

Does Bender Speak Binary?

On occasion, in the classroom, I often direct students to specific articles in a given issue of the New York Times, the Wall Street Journal or the International Herald Tribune. I ask them to find among the chosen pieces, evidence of the particular theoretical concept under discussion in class. I run this exercise usually after a particular heavy dose of economic theory and it has many reasons to recommend it. It is intended to show that there is life beyond theory, that the theoretical concept has legs, that the theory conveys a deeper understanding of a particular topic presented, that microeconomic theory has continuity and generality, that theory steels the analytical mind and is not just a device concocted by instructors to torture undergrads. The results of the exercise are often sobering – revealing considerable detail about my instructing inabilities; but it is generally fun.
Take for example the following three pieces that appeared on this past Sunday July 26, 2010 in the hardcopy edition of the NY Times. There was an article on the ideological character of the recent Supreme Court by Adam Lipvak (this article appeared online on July 24th), an article on Snooki (also available online) and a book review written by David Gilbert. Task: point out and discuss the concept in decision-making (collapsing of attributes; aka tree pruning) present in these three articles.
Adam Litvak front page article, (Court Under Roberts Most Conservative in Decades) was explaining the ideological tilt to the right – towards a more conservative position - of the Supreme Court. The article turns heavily on its reliance on extant Political Science empirical work on the binary categorization of Supreme Court rulings.
Snooki was also featured; Cathy Horyn’s Snooki’s Time is an appropriately weird article or a weird character. And for those of you who have been away time traveling – Snooki is now officially hot (well, certainly the show is, Jersey Shore). The article accurately described the frustration, apprehension and disgust voiced by Italian-American associations at the reductionist and limited portrayal of comical (but more often sad and sorry) characters in the show– like Snooki - who happen to identify themselves as Italian-American. Last, Dan Gilbert was reviewing yet one more book on errors in decision-making. (Daniel Gilbert, The Error of Our Ways, a book review of Kathryn’s Schulz’s, Being Wrong: Adventures in the Margin of Error. (Ecco/HarperColins)). It’s been awhile now that these books bridging the real world and academic results and debates in Empirical Decision-Making have been entering the popular press. Starting with (at least for me) Massimo Piatelli-Palmarini’s Inevitable Illusions: How Mistakes of Reason Rule our Minds (John Wiley & Sons, 1994) in the early 90s - till now - is a tad short of two decades. Generally, these books illustrate in a very entertaining manner how particular human behavioral traits, hard-wired over evolutionary time, are still present with us - and largely very useful when we make decisions in the face of uncertainty. But often they lead us astray. The key to eliciting good decision-making is either to recognize such pitfalls and avoid them altogether or to change the institutional structure to elicit the correct decision – rather than the more-common-but-potentially-erroneous hard-wired one. The latter is an example of what Sunstein-Thaler call ‘nudging;’ an important plank in the Obama administration’s conceptual elements underscoring recent legislative proposals.
It is generally well known that humans opt for stark simplicity in entertaining concepts. Simply put: it makes decision making easy. If you know that the pointy-headed guys are all mean and bad then it’s not that hard to decide to cross the street when a pointy headed fellow is coming straight at you. Survival is at stake. Thus, it makes sense to take and interpret cues (attributes) around and surrounding a particular ‘uncategorized’ fellow – especially those who don’t have the tell-tale pointy head – and categorize them into pointy heads or not. And you tell your friend what you have decided– ‘cause then the group benefits from the individual’s experience.
And this is exactly the point with Litvak on the Supreme Court and with Horyn, Snooki and Italian-Americans, an issue highlighted in the literature in which Dan Gilbert writes – as per the book review. The dots are connected. At all times the necessary binary categorization is useful to some – but much less – and even offensive - to others. That’s because by its very nature categorization necessarily leaves stuff out.
Categorization for purposes of decision-making is not conceptually complicated – although it does get operationally trickier. First, we set forth the attributes that constitute the category we want to abridge: thus, one is Liberal or Italian American. But agreeing on the relevant attributes that constitute that category is not that simple – what if I believe that people who wear glasses should constitute a criteria for being liberal – and you don’t? Or left-handedness? Or how ‘bout skin color? Can we settle this statistically, or mathematically? The answer is yes –but again, it requires agreeing on the selection algorithm – an algorithm that is going to decide which attribute goes in or not. In other words, we’ve just pushed the problem into the next round - unsolved.
What is certain is that we end up categorizing with error. ‘Tis inevitable. And some are willing to trade error (and any blowback it may generate) for discourse, or political analysis or cultural commentary. But others who are aware of the constraints imposed by this reductionism should refuse. Isn’t this self evident? Sonia and Clarence are hugely complex intellectuals capable of outlining and explaining their positions in great detail; and the do. Italian Americans are a hugely varied lot. Why reduce their sophistication and variation onto a mere category? Your analytical capacity is greatly diminished by doing this and you do your audience a disservice.
I should mention that there are other ways of dealing with the possibly offensive and certainly silly nature of binary reductionism. Amartya Sen, for example, and at the risk of oversimplifying his thinking in Identity and Violence: the Illusion of Destiny (Norton, 2006) embraces the idea of multiple affiliations: as my wife says, she is not only a ‘woman.’ She is also a mother, a republican, a neighbor of Hamden, CT., a teacher, a mentor, a daughter – well, you get the picture. Try messing with that!
What is the takeaway from this? Let’s strive for consistency and understand the context and the exercise. If you find yourself with a bunch of your buds having some brewskys and chatting away about how Sonia is ‘way too liberal’ or Clarence is ‘so far right he ran out of the page’ then, let it be. If on the other hand, you are asked by an instructor or a boss or in a serious conversation to analyze or address a point, then refuse the behavioral trap and say no to frivolous and uninformative reductionism – embrace the complexity.
And about bender - I know he can read binary (see The Honking Bender) - but does he speak binary? Post away.

A.E. Rodriguez
(arodriguez@newhaven.edu)
Monday, July 26, 2010

Monday, May 10, 2010

Parallel Takes

We all have those who we revere, our demi-gods, mortals whom we admire and who easily capture our attention with the power of their words, thoughts or worldview. Anything Harry Turtledove writes - I read. And the Gingrich-Forstchen combo could publish their weekly supermarket shopping list and Amazon, under standing instructions to flag anything of theirs, immediately would ship it my way.
Examining parallel histories, - the retelling of familiar events in worlds that are quite familiar not only captures our imaginations but allows us to examine the outer environs of the possible. And no one enlivens the journey into parallel worlds better than Turtledove.
Counterfactual history, which entails constructing contrasting takes on past events –enriches our appreciation for what actually transpired, forcing us to acknowledge – among other things - that there are many paths that can reach a known outcome (and many paths that don’t, despite common beginnings). But to engage in such an exercise, - as do Gingrich and Forstchen in Gettysburgh (NY: St. Martin’s Press, 2003), amidst the still tender sentiments of civil war history (among many quarters) grip not only our imagination but also our hearts, emotions and even latent hatreds.
Then there are those writers who are provocative, entertaining and downright fun. Malcolm Gladwell for example, Steven Pinker’s unseemly and, in my opinion, undeserved thrashing notwithstanding (here), has the power to engage and teach, all while being hugely entertaining. I don’t know why Pinker was so bilious; perhaps he had just finished refereeing a paper for the Journal of Theoretical Biology or something and had failed to adjust his scopes to reality. (We will return to this theme up on a later blog.) Gladwell is a superb expositor; I routinely use his columns and podcasts in my classes – I think, to great effect. (Gladwell’s response to Pinker here.)
Then there are those authors and commentators we are now obliged to read or listen to keep up professionally, – anointed superstars like Paul Krugman. Every so often one of these superstars rips into another one in our constellation. These swipes engender a most unpleasant intellectual dissonance, shocks that upset my quest for that increasingly (as of late) elusive reflective equilibrium.
Such was the case with Krugman’s post in the New York Times of September 2009. In this piece, Krugman unleashed a massive broadside at mainstream (primarily Chicago) economics, disparaging with special gusto the work of John Cochrane, Robert Lucas and Robert Barro – bona fide economic grandees. Cochrane, Lucas and Barro are financial macroeconomists – and I, frankly am not that familiar with their work – beyond the obligatory classics. Besides they can take care of themselves – see here for Cochrane’s response to Krugman.

But the NYT piece as hardly the first Krugman nastygram. He appears to have warmed up to the task a few months earlier. In his three-part Lionel Robbins Memorial Lecture at the London School of Economics last June 8,9, & 10 2009 (which you can find here; the podcasts are organized by event date) Professor Krugman held forth on what he called ‘depression economics,’ probing the causes and appraising the recovery prospects of the current economic crisis. In doing so he does not hesitate to lambaste those he holds responsible. Regardless of your opinion of Krugman - or his abrasiveness – the Robbins lectures are a must.
Krugman’s recounting of Great Depression economics history is naturally, a self-serving interpretation. In his lecture, he opens a particular line of argument by sarcastically observing how the interpretation of Great Depression history has lately become a tool of ideology-laden economic policy debates. This observation doesn’t prevent him from plunging into his particular take on depression economics. Again, nothing truly objectionable here – ‘tis the nature of policy debates.
But when the narrative set forth naturally leads to an implicit claim of exclusivity, that is to say that when he argues that his interpretation of the actual economic path traversed is THE only possible plausible explanation Krugman treads thin ice. Harry Turtledove and Newt Gingrich fans would immediately recognize the logical fallacy in this reasoning – even if they had no idea what the NRA (the National Recovery Administration) and the FTC (the Federal Trade Commission) do. Krugman’s explanation as to the roots and persistence of the Great Depression, – and all other explanations for that matter – have to necessarily remain subjective and, so some extent, speculative. To fully understand the underlying causes of the persistence of the great depression, one would have to appreciate any number of causes and confounders leading to any number of both similar and varying alternative paths/explanations. For example, we would need to understand what would have happened (to output and employment over so many years) had real wages not risen, had FDR not vilified Wall Street, had Smoot-Hawley been rescinded, and so forth, ad infinitum. The presence of a multitude of ‘but-for,’ plausible alternatives is what leads Gingrich and Forstchen to explore what would have transpired had Lee prevailed at Gettysburg.
And so does Malcolm Gladwell although he appears to forget sometimes. In Outliers (NY: Little, Brown & Co., 2008) – Gladwell explores the necessary link between success, talent and opportunity – unwrapping one strand of a possible multiple. Thus, one is led to understand how Bill Gates did not just spring out of the ether fully clothed in his magnificent brilliance. Rather, Gladwell carefully notes how Gates’ affluent origins enabled him to have access to one of the earliest computers in his hometown of Seattle, just down the road from his suburban home – where he honed his skills, imagination and inquisitiveness. Perhaps; but do we know whether Gates would have grown up to achieve the same success had he taken a different path that one fortuitous night – say attend the local boy scouts meeting instead? And on the other hand what about the many other affluent, smart kids who had access to countless gadgets all across America? What happened to them? Or for that matter those who lived on the other side of the tracks but did quite well - nonetheless. All plausible, all realized. But the point is we don’t know. And we can’t know and therefore Gladwell’s thesis remains but a (damn interesting) thesis.
On to Krugman. One would have to determine whether, during the Depression, the alternatives not chosen would have led us to the same levels of output and unemployment and the 10 years of depression we lived through. Only by forming an estimate of possible outcomes - the full array of possible paths leading to the observed (as well as those unobserved outcomes) - could we ascertain the validity of Krugman’s claim, or Arthur Schlesinger Jr.’s (The Crisis of the Old Order) or John Kenneth Galbraith’s (The Great Crash)– for that matter. Uncertainty, Professor Krugman, is a condition of our environment.
And it is the relevance of the all-encompassing pervasiveness of uncertainty the precise point of Amity Shlaes wonderful book – The Forgotten Man: a New History of the Great Depression (New York: Harper Collins, 2007).
The phrase – the forgotten man – has suffered a lot of abuse over the years. It originates with William Graham Sumner and alluded to the normal Joe – like all of us who run afoul of the resulting regulatory morass that seems to succeed economic crisis. Forgotten men are those of us who don’t have lobbyists representing our interests in Washington; those of us who have no connections at the Federal Reserve; those of us who know no one at Treasury. Yet it is us who get stuck with the bill when the piƱata is over.
Franklin Delano Roosevelt brought the phrase back cast in an entirely different light. In FDR’s hand, the forgotten man became the one totally abandoned by his government, the unwitting victim of unfettered free markets, the pawns in banker’s greedy lust for wealth – at all costs.
In rescuing Sumner’s forgotten man, Ms. Shlaes deftly embraces as her organizing theme the fear and apprehension that permeated America during the depression years. In no small part this uncertainty was the result of the grip on our mental schemas of the unpredictable, erratic and often contradictory policies coming out of Washington during the 1930’s – the FDR years. The government’s involvement in the economic recovery process exacerbates the problems derived from uncertainty instead of alleviating them – the idea of ‘regime uncertainty’ originating with Professor Robert Higgs. Professor Higgs makes the case that an uncertain political climate spooked investors (and a great many other folks) and thus slowed the recovery in the late 1930’s. There was among the populace during the depression an inability to sensibly gauge the impact of the politics behind the government’s recovery effort. There existed a sense that the government was headed in a direction that promised to curtail or reduce the success of a man’s private investment plans. Thus, ordinary folks adjusted their plans accordingly – and the depression lived on.
Professor Krugman dismisses Ms. Shlaes book as “massively uninformed” (in the 2nd Robbins lecture). It is not clear why Professor Krugman is so uncharitably dismissive of Ms. Shlaes work. Perhaps it is because Ms. Shlaes is a darling of the Cato crowd – Professor Krugman’s unyielding intellectual adversaries. Perhaps Professor Krugman believes that accepting Ms. Shlaes thesis is unfathomable if applied to present events. Yet even his fellow Keynesian Judge Richard Posner worries about this. Here is Niall Ferguson in the New York Times Book Review (May 9, 2010) writing about the recently converted (to Keynesianism) Judge Posner’s new book, “By directing their fire at bankers, Posner suggest, legislators want us to forget that among ‘the major culprits in our present economic distress’ have been ‘government officials.’ Moreover, the new regulations being discussed in Congress are tending to increase uncertainty in financial markets, another drag on recovery. “
Perhaps Professor Krugman did not read Ms. Shlaes’ book. Had he done so he would have recognized Knightian uncertainty settled in the background of Ms. Shlaes book and before that, snuggling within Professor Higgs’writings. In his third and last Robbins lecture - Krugman yanks – uber-Keynsian Hyman Mynsky back from (relative) obscurity – and sets him front and center as the intellectual flavor of the month. The irony here is that if there ever was anyone obsessive about the impact of uncertainty on economic performance, ‘twas Minsky.
A.E. Rodriguez
May 10, 2010
(arodriguez@newhaven.edu)